Introduction: Street Vendors in the Postmodern World
Or, "What the heck do Street Vendors have to do with Postmodernity?"
By
John C. Cross, Ph.D.

(C) John Cross, 1998

**THIS IS A DRAFT INTRODUCTION FOR A NEW VOLUME--PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE, DOWNLOAD OR PRINT WITHOUT PERMISSION**

After reading, please send comments to the author      

 

The reader picking up this volume may be perplexed by the conjunction of street
vending and the postmodern in the title. We typically think of street vending as a part of
the premodern, traditional economic order that survives only on the fringes of modern
society. How could something that we think of as premodern be associated with the
postmodern age? Our reasons for presenting the reader with this conundrum is rooted in
our research on street vending in various different countries—research that we began with
the common assumption in mind that street vending should, by all logical criteria,
eventually disappear. What we found, however, is that street vending, despite being under
constant attack, is a thriving and growing trade for reasons tied directly to the current
changes in the global economy that have been associated by many authors with
postmodernity.

      It is appropriate here to make a distinction between postmodernism and
postmodernity. As Lemert notes, “This distinction is inherent in the difference between
speaking of postmodernity, a purportedly new state of world affairs, and
postmodernism, a theory or cultural attitude towards those affairs.” (Lemert 1997:26) It
is not the objective of this book to delve into the various debates within the realm of
postmodernism, focused as they are in the areas of art, literature, philosophy and the
sociology of science. While these are fascinating in themselves, they require serious
attention that cannot be afforded in an introduction to a book of this nature, which
already has far too much territory to cover. But we are concerned with the question of
postmodernity and how this has, or could have, an influence on the economic conditions
of those who turn to street vending.

      While there is some debate about whether or not it is appropriate to use the term
postmodernity to describe today’s world, “At the least it is obvious that the world which
for a long time has been thought of as ‘modern’ is experience a crisis of grave and global
proportions.” (Lemert 1997:32) Lemert associates this crisis with three factors: the
collapse of the Euro-American colonial system; the disappearance of a coherent imperial
world center and; the rise of a global opposition to a single, unified world culture
associated with Euro-American value systems. These broader changes are also associated
with changes in the global economic system that have seriously undermined the central
logic of modernism itself—the Fordist/Keynesian economic order. This system
emphasized, on the one hand, the centralization of production and distribution in the
hands of mega-corporations built around the theory of economies of scale. On the other
hand, it emphasized the regulatory role of the state in managing relations between
workers, managers, owners, and consumers. This regulatory role is the basis of the
massive increase in the size of the state bureaucracy at every level even as it has
intervened into every aspect of social life, a process shown clearly in the historical
archaeology of Michel Foucault.

      Obviously, this modern project began long before the advent of Ford and Keynes.
Many tie its origins to the enlightenment (Harvey 1990), but the Fordist/Keynesian
approach to economic management, the former at the corporate level and the latter at the
state level, exemplified the process and theory behind economic centralization and
regulation that became a hallmark of the “modern” world, whether it was capitalist or
socialist. While the grand rationale behind modernism was the creation of more and more
“efficient” and “productive” individuals by controlling and ordering the relations between
individuals, in fact modern efficiency and productivity could only fully thrive under
optimal conditions that had to be molded gradually over time. These conditions not only
required massive changes in state structure, roles and revenues, business organization,
factory structure and market systems, but also in the very culture and social life of
individuals, families and communities. As a total system, it required that every aspect of
society should be molded according to its requirements. Fordism represents above all the
formal recognition that mass production requires a mass market, and that mass markets
don’t just exist—they must be manufactured!

    This need to manufacture a “modern” society is best expressed in its ideal version
by the height of modernist architecture and urban planning, which are at the same time of
key relevance to the issue of urban street markets. Long seen as the best representative of
modernist design was Le Corbusier, a French architect who influenced the field greatly in
the mid-war period with his emphasis on grand scale design and planning. In his 1923
keynote text, Towards a New Architecture, Le Corbusier (1996) expressed the modern
focus on the re-creation of society through a planned structure that would assign each
individual to his or her place in life, regulating and caring for each need and demand:

      “…without plan there can be neither grandeur of aim and expression, nor rhythm,
      nor mass, nor coherence. Without plan we have the sensation, so insupportable to
      man, of shapelessness, of poverty, of disorder, of wilfulness.” (1996:207)
      Thus does Corbusier exhibit the modernist dream of a model society run from

above. One can imagine that street vending would have little refuge in such a world. In this
ideal, everything is ordered, efficient and structured. Nothing is left to chance. It is little
wonder, indeed, that Corbusier, like many others in Europe at this time, was attracted to
more and more authoritarian regimes that could put such an order into effect. The result
could perhaps be more appropriately termed the modernist nightmare, as Fascism and
Stalinist socialism arose to crash against eachother and against the more liberal (but no less
modern) democracies in the second world war (Harvey 1990:128-9). The same modernist
nightmare influenced such novels as Huxley’s Brave New World and Orwell’s 1984,
differing versions of the same theme of modernism gone wild.

      Modernism did not go wild, however. While its heyday was reached in the 1950s
and 1960s, with rapid economic growth in the United States and, later, Europe and Japan,
the 1970s began to show cracks in the basic economic structure of modernism itself. Not
only did growth slow down in the U.S. as it was faced with increased competition from
Europe and Japan, but unemployment and inflation began to grow in all these areas. Third
World growth strategies, built around protectionist import substitution policies, also
began to enter into crisis at this point (Harvey 1990:141).

      Even at the height of modernist growth, not everyone was equally privileged. The
dynamics of race and gender in the U.S. meant that white males obtained the best jobs
opened up in the factories and corporate offices that opened up by the millions during
this period. In Third World nations, growth benefited an even smaller class of elite
workers and managers, leaving most people outside the modernist dream. In terms of
meeting the needs of the poor, “Modernism failed as mass-housing and city building
partly because it failed to communicate with its inhabitants and users who might not have
liked the style, understood what it meant or even known how to use it.” (Jencks
1996:475) Thus, those left out of the dream could neither benefit from it, nor fully escape
from its effects.
      Nor did the decline of modernism bring the poor any direct advantages.
Harvey defines this process as a shift from Fordism to flexible accumulation. This
process “spelled danger for traditionally organized businesses, sparking a wave of
bankruptcies, plant closures, deindustrialization, and restructuring…” (Harvey 1990:155)
The economies of scale sought by Fordist mass production were supplanted, at least to a
large degree, by economies of flexibility. In effect the growth of regulatory and labor
power in the first world economies grew to the degree that they produced a competitive
disadvantage, leading “either to the rise of entirely new industrial forms or to the
integration of Fordism with a network of subcontracting and ‘outsourcing’ to give greater
flexibility in the face of heightened competition and greater risks.” (Harvey 1990:155-6)
In effect, the modernist compromise whereby workers gave up control over their labor in
exchange for a modicum of wealth and security unraveled in the face of competitive
pressures. Not only were workers paid less in the aggregate, but they also took greater
risks as jobs moved rapidly to find the lowest wages.

      The “great sucking sound to the south” that Ross Perot alluded to in the
debate over the passage of the North American Free Trade Agreement with Mexico and
Canada in 1993 had really begun decades before as plants and production had relocated to
Mexico, Taiwan, South Korea and myriad other nations where labor costs were lower and
regulatory enforcement was partial.
      Postmodernity, then, reflects a stage in economic development in which
capital is free to go wherever profits are higher without the need to worry about the
welfare of workers or consumers. Investment is made based upon the assumption that
consumers will be found elsewhere in the world market, thus escaping from the Fordist
need to pay wages and benefits high enough so that the workers could themselves
consume the products they produce.

    As far as the Third World is concerned, postmodernism implies business as usual.
While new investment pours in, wages levels remain low for the vast majority of the
population. For the first world, however, the effect is to produce new forms of
employment that lack the security and wage guarantees of modern industry. The result is
an increase in the labor market without, however, a corresponding increase in the average
wage. People are paid less for doing more: a violation of the very laws of supply and
demand that throws the entire logic of classical economics into question.

Street vending, modernity, postmodernity and the informal economy
 

    Street vending usually falls within the category of informal economic activity.
This category includes “the production and exchange of legal goods and services that
involves the lack of appropriate business permits, violation of zoning codes, failure to
report tax liability, non-compliance with labor regulations governing contracts and work
conditions, and/or the lack of legal guarantees in relations with suppliers and clients.”
(Cross 1998a: 580). This definition does not imply a “black/white” definition of
informality, but rather the possibility of differing degree of informality, since an
enterprise or business relation could be formal by some criteria, but informal by others.
For example, a workshop or street stall may have a permit, but not pay taxes. Or it may
pay taxes but not have a legal contract with its employees. Another dimension of
informality that is little discussed in the literature but very often important in terms of
individual motivation is the actual social relationship between economic actors: one might
compare, for example, a consumer at a Walmart or McDonalds, who has a purely formal
relationship with the enterprise and its staff, and the customer of a vegetable stall, where
interpersonal relations and trust become important, for example, in the question of
whether the produce is fresh or the balance fairly weighted.

      The relationship between the informal economy and modernity was obviously
problematic from the start, given the discussion in the previous section. As the state’s
regulatory system expanded to encompass every aspect of economic activity in order to
regulate and order the relations between owners, employees and consumers, it has become
more and more difficult for the poor, in particular, to establish businesses that met all of
the growing legal requirements. Not only are these requirements costly, they may require
the assistance of lawyers, accountants or other specialists—services typically out of the
reach of the poor. De Soto (1989) argues that this over-regulation is itself directly
responsible for spurring the growth of the informal economy by creating an
entrepreneurial incentive to skirt the regulatory system, thus allowing them to compete
with multi-national corporations. But the problem is a bit more complex.

      While the growth of the modern corporation, which used mass production to
reduce the units costs of these requirements, allowed these costs to be passed on to
consumers, mass production is limited in its capacity to meet the needs of the population:
it is only feasible where there is a mass market, meaning a sufficiently large pool of
potential consumers with both the income and the desire to purchase the product. Luxury
niche markets, on the one hand, and mass poverty markets, on the other, both present
problems for mass production and distribution chains. For luxury goods, the limited
market niche itself reduces the benefits of economies of scale. In the poverty stricken
areas of the Third World, and in the inner city areas of the First, the cost of many mass
produced articles is still to high for the consumer market, assuming that all the production
and distribution costs of bringing the product to the consumer are formalized.

      This has several repercussions that can be best demonstrated by the use of
examples. First, supermarket chains, which are the quintessence of modernist retailing, are
almost always far more visible in middle class residential areas than in either wealthy or
poor neighborhoods. Despite their efficiency when presented with a mass consumer
market able to pay their formal costs, they cannot compete, apparently, with either the
boutiques of wealthy areas nor the small stores and street markets in poor areas. (Tokman
1978) Where formal regulations are strictly applied, as is more usually the case in the
First World, this has created the curious phenomena that food and other essential goods
are more expensive in poor neighborhoods than they are in middle class areas. However,
where there is an active informal economy, street markets and informal producers can
step in to fill this niche passing on the savings of their lack of legality (and their added
flexibility) on to the poor of these areas.

      To take another example, many formal products are available in poorer
areas, but only because they are provided by informal stores and stalls. The popularity of
Coca Cola, Pepsi and innumerable other snack and consumer products is made possible in
Third World countries by the small-scale distribution channels of these products that
makes ample use of informal and semiformal distributors and retails outlets that reduce
the final cost to the consumer in poor areas. Alonso (1981), for example, uses his study
of neighborhood stores in Mexico City to argue that they are, in fact, a form of disguised
employees of these large corporations. Bromley (1978) makes a similar argument with
respect to some street vendors (particularly ice cream and newspaper vendors) in
Columbia.

      Thirdly, of course, is the production of goods by informal enterprises—small
workshops, homeworkers and even “sweatshop” factories—that either produce directly
for consumers or, because of competitive outsourcing by formal firms fighting to lower
their costs, as suppliers of labor-intensive intermediate goods for formal factories and
distributors. While this area of the informal economy lies outside the purview of this
anthology, it is probably one of the most studied areas of the informal economy given the
bias against retail activities in the literature (a bias that this anthology hopes to alleviate).

      Finally, in reference to luxury markets, the growth of the informal economy in
Southern Italy and Miami has been tied to the growth of luxury niche markets in these
areas (Portes et al, 1989). In the case of street vending this is most apparent in the growth
of “Farmers Markets” in the United States and their equivalents in other First World
nations, that sell high priced vegetables and fruits to discerning consumers who may want
organic foods of feel assured of the freshness of their produce.

      Going back to Le Corbusier’s modernist vision of urban space, the informal
economy, and street vending in particular, would very much provoke in the modernist
that “sensation, so insupportable to man, of shapelessness, of poverty, of disorder, of
wilfulness.” To the extent that the modernist ideal was shared by elites in the First and
Third Worlds alike (particularly in as much as Third World elites considered
“modernization” to imply the approximation of the modernist ideal in external form), the
presence of large street markets were the clearest sign of the “disorder” and “wilfulness”
of the informal economy that must needs be stamped out.

      In his classic study, Peddlers and Princes, (1963) the anthropologist Clifford
Geertz reflected the belief shared by most scholars at the time—that street markets and
bazaars were part of a romantic past that had little place in the “modern” world.
According to the modernist developmental vision that permeated the scholarship of the
1950s and 1960s, these forms of commerce were seen as backward, inefficient and
detrimental to national development schemes, taking up and wasting resources that could
be better spent in more productive fashion. From a cultural perspective, Geertz argued
that the "bazaar economy" hampered the development of a western style "firm-centered"
economy. For example, he argued that .the practice of haggling that he saw as typical of
bazaar settings focuses competition onto the relationship between the vendor and the
buyer over the value of the goods involved rather than between vendors themselves. This,
he argued, leads traders to act speculatively and opportunistically, since,"...the aim is
always to get as much as possible out of the deal immediately at hand. The (bazaar) trader
is perpetually looking for a chance to make a smaller or larger killing, not attempting to
build up a clientele or a steadily growing business" (35). Even though it employs huge
numbers of individuals, Geertz maintained that this system, "has the disadvantage that it
turns even the established businessman away from an interest in reducing costs and
developing markets and toward petty speculation and short-run opportunism" (28-29).
Similarly, Bairoch (1973), writing for the International Labor Office, lamented the
development of an “over-distended tertiary”—encompassing services and commerce--
that threatened to undermine national development plans by placing a drag on the
economy. Why this growth was occurring despite expectations to the contrary was little
considered, however, beyond suggestions of cultural and educational backwardness.

      It is interesting to remark on McGee’s (1973) study on street vending in Hong
Kong, a rapidly industrializing colony at the time. He notes that industrialists appealed to
the colonial administration to repress street vending because of a labor shortage in the
growing industrial sector at the time, attacking vendors for their “laziness” in choosing
street vending over factory work. The fact is, McGee points out, that street vendors
simply felt they could earn more on the streets than in the wage sector. In my own
research vendors have many times claimed that street vending is also a life style choice,
allowing them greater personal freedom and flexibility (see also Bobea, this volume).

      Street vending thus came under savage attack throughout the modernist era. While
one of the criticisms lodged against this activity was its purported inefficiency, the real
problem was it was too competitive with formal retail outlets, unless they were located in
optimal “modern” areas. Supermarkets could not put street vendors out of business
through market mechanisms, they had to use the police system to do it. The solution,
therefore was to ban or over-regulate street vendors while at the same time redesigning
urban spaces in which they could no longer exist. Suburban subdivisions, urban decay and
urban renewal projects were all a vigorous part of this process in the First World. In the
Third World, the same processes were obviously put in place, but with varying success
due to the lack of modernist penetration of society and the increased power of those in
the informal economy themselves to evade or resist the modernist encroachment on their
livelihoods. In Mexico City, for example, an extraordinarily expensive program managed
to banish street vending for just under a decade in the 1960s, but it subsequently
reemerged stronger than ever (Cross 1998b; and this volume). In Los Angeles, California,
on the other hand, where street vending was also effectively banished in the late 1950s, it
didn’t become a significant factor again until the 1980s.

      But reemerge they did, as the modernist dream crumbled into postmodern reality.
In doing so, however, they did not simply signal a return to a romanticized past, but
created a rational reaction to the economic, cultural and social world of today.
Postmodernism as a movement, if we can think of it as such, is concerned first and
foremost with the individual’s attempt to regain control over their lives—control that is
lost in today’s society of mass-production factories and corporate offices. This is
reflected in the renewed growth of small businesses since the 1980s, as the middle class
seeks to avoid the control of salaried labor. But many are finding that the burden of
regulations means that they have simply exchanged one form of control for another.
Another option is the informal economy, particularly for the poor of the Third World.
Street vending, since it takes advantage of public space—and this is in fact where most of
the struggle lies—and thus minimizes overhead costs of rent and utilities, is ideally suited
for informal growth, to the extent that it can withstand hostile attempts to over-regulate
or eliminate it, either through evasion, negotiation, or conflict.

Organization of the volume

      The research articles included in this anthology reflect a variety of theoretical and
practical perspectives of street vending in today’s postmodern world. While few of them
are explicitly postmodern in their approach, they offer to the reader a broad
understanding of the dynamics of today’s street vendors and street markets, both in the
First World and in the Third. We have organized these contributions loosely into four
broad categories, although most of them overlap in terms of their topic and approach into
several possible categories.

      In the first section, focusing on research questions, Ray Bromley provides a broad
overview of street vending, public policy, and private initiatives, based on decades of
research in a variety of different nations in Chapter 2. He brings this research to bear on a
descriptive and explanatory analysis of the paradoxical coexistence of policies to
persecute, regulate, tolerate, and promote street vending. He discusses how these policies
are applied to influence the spacio-temporal distribution of street vending, the number of
vendors, their trading practices and the types of goods and services they can offer. He
discusses the mix of policies in the context of political and economic conditions that vary
over time and place which reflect a dynamic equilibrium between conflicting views and
interest groups.

      In Chapter 3, Steve Balkin and Alfonso Morales show how street vending has
become integrated into the world wide web through a web site organized by the authors
that has assisted the U.S. Supreme Court in a case involving art vendors in New York
City and has become a forum for the exchange of research on this activity between
scholars and practitioners in the First and Third Worlds.

      In the second section, focusing on micro and meso case studies, I provide in
Chapter 4 an ethnographic discussion of the history of a family of street vendors in
Mexico City. The chapter illustrates a family case history of a family based enterprise
that began during a period of severe repression against vending but survived to go on to
become an entrepreneurial career path for their children. By expanding laterally, rather
than vertically, the family is able to establish stalls in various market places in the city
simultaneously while pooling common resources in order to maximize efficiency.

      In chapter 5, Dominick Dellino provides an economic anthropology analysis of
street vending in Nicaragua during a transition period from Sandinista to post-Sandinista
rule. Locating his work in an historical narrative, Dellino finds that the flexibility of street
vending allows informal street traders a special advantage due to their ability to adapt
rapidly during a period of hyperinflation—a situation that changed with the advent of
tighter inflationary control and extremely high unemployment under the Chamorro regime.

      In chapter 6, Recep Varcin unpacks the typical assumption of street vending: that
it is generally individualistic and competitive in his research on street markets in Ankara,
Turkey. Varcin carefully shows how market traders make economic decisions in a
competitive environment, and identifies three groups of vendors in terms of the goals and
strategies that they pursue: profit maximizers, risk minimizers, and marginal traders. The
chapter explores the significance of economies of scale, ethnicity and localism as three
important “externally identifiable” characteristics around which market traders mobilize
their resources and restrict the access of opportunity to “eligibles.”

      In chapter 7, Stein Nesvag studies another approach to street vending—ethnic
niche markets—with an analysis of African medicine vendors in Durban, South Africa.
Nesvag’s analysis is further enriched because the research crosses the boundaries between
a culturally repressive apartheid period and a post-apartheid explosion of self-realization
on the part of the majority African population. Still, he shows that even in the post-
apartheid era street vending is seen as an eyesore and a problem, creating a complex
political dynamic with a new regime whose legitimacy is based on its African roots.

      Finally, in Chapter 8, Elena Obukuva provides an interesting study of another
niche market for street vendors—newspaper venders in Nigeria. Obukuva shows how the
formal newspaper industry has become completely dependent on the informal
distribution channels provided by distributors and vendors. Studying this process during
a period of economic decline and heightened political insecurity and repression, Obukuva
shows how the informal distributors have adapted to declining incomes and government
repression, helping to assure the continuation of the newspaper industry.

      In the third section we focus on cultural issues of how street vendors are defined
by society, by elites and by themselves. In chapter 9, Bobea provides an ethnographic
analysis of the “hidden transcripts” upon which Dominican women in New York organize
their vending businesses and survive in the face of typically oppressive state regulation
and control. Bobea counters the negative stereotype of vendors as agents of disorder and
disease to reveal the beneficial hidden transcripts of independence and self-esteem within
street commerce.

      In chapter 11, Ann Dupuis and Anne de Bruin study an ethnic street market in
New Zealand. As New Zealand has reacted to global transformation and the new
international division of labor, the national response to these changes has led to radical
welfare state restructuring. The result has been high unemployment rates, especially
among the ethnic Maoris and Pacific Islanders who live in Otara, a suburb of Auckland.
Dupuis and de Bruin focus their analysis on how the street market allows individuals and
the community to react and adapt to these changes, allowing for the expression of
positive individual and ethnic identities.

      In the final section, we turn to political issues related to street vending. In chapter
12 Loretta Bass examines the problems faced by vendors in Senegal when city officials
widen a street adjacent to their market. Hierarchies based on gender, age and class define
the power and available material resources that the market sellers were able to marshal to
influence their own situations in this context of rapid social change. Bass shows how
these factors intersect to determine whether vendors are positively or negatively affected
by the changes.

      In chapter 13, Loran Cutsinger shows how officials in Barbados have attempted to
relocate a street market in a tourist area because of the “inconvenience” of the market to
the tourist industry, even while street stalls are used as a tourist symbol, reproduced on
mugs, t-shirts and other tourist items. Cutsinger shows how street vendors have emerged
as an important part of the tourist trade in Barbados, tied into the postmodern emphasis
on “authentic” tourist experiences, but also how the reality of street markets clashes with
government concerns to present a “modern” image to the tourist market.

      Chapter 15 presents a reanalysis of my research on the political struggle of street
vendors in Mexico City as a form of postmodern social movement responding to
government attempts to “order” street vending in that city. By looking at two historical
periods of government repression against street vending, the first on a city-wide level and
the second in the city center, I compare between “modernist” and “postmodernist”
government attacks on street vending, and how street vendors have adapted to challenge
the government’s control of public space.

      Finally, in the conclusion, Alfonso Morales and Steve Balkin present a convincing
argument in favor of street vending in the postmodern world. Rather than being seen as a
problem, they urge government officials to understand the benefits that street markets can
bring to urban areas in terms of jobs, service provision, and community development, and
to work with street vendors rather than against them to resolve problems that emerge.

Bibliography

Alonso Jorge, et al
1980             Lucha Urbana y Acumulación de Capital. Ed. La Casa Chata, Mexico City.
Bairoch, Paul
1973             Urban Unemployment in Developing Countries. International Labor
      Office, Geneva.
Bromley, Ray
1978             "Organization, Regulation and Exploitation in the So-Called `Urban Informal
      Sector': The Street Traders of Cali, Colombia" in World Development 6:1161-
      1172.
Cross, John
1998a             “Informal Sector”, pp. 580-582 in Encyclopedia of Political Economy, Routledge:
      London.
1998b             Informal Politics: Street Vendors and the State in Mexico City. Stanford
      University Press: Stanford.
De Soto
1989             The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. Harper & Row:
      New York.
Geertz, Clifford

1963             Peddlers & Princes: Social Change and Economic Modernization in Two
      Indonesian Towns
. University of Chicago Press. Chicago.
Harvey, David
1990             The Condition of Postmodernity. Blackwell publishers: Cambridge, MA. &
      Oxford.
Jencks, Charles
1996             “What is Postmodernism” in Lawrence Cahoone, ed. From Modernism to
      Postmodernism: An Anthology
. Blackwell publishers: Oxford.
Le Corbusier
1996             “Towards a New Architecture” in Lawrence Cahoone, ed. From Modernism to
      Postmodernism: An Anthology
. Blackwell publishers: Oxford.
Lemert, Charles
1997             Postmodernism Is Not What You Think. Blackwell publishers: Oxford.
McGee, T. G.
1973             Hawkers in Hong Kong. Center for Asian Studies Monographs and Occasional
      Papers, No. 17. University of Hong Kong.
Portes, Alejandro, Manuel Castells, and Lauren A. Benton
1989             “Conclusion: The Policy Implications of Informality,” pp. 298-311 in Alejandro
      Portes, Manuel Castells and Lauren A. Benton (eds.), The Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developed Countries. John Hopkins University
      Press: Baltimore.
Tokman, Victor E.
1978             "Competition between the Informal and Formal Sectors in Retailing: The
      Case of Santiago" in World Development, 6:1187-1198.